In March 2012, McAllen, Texas, was hit with a once-in-a-generation disaster, a supercell thunderstorm that battered the city with 75mph wind gusts, flash floods, and hailstones the size of baseballs in the middle of the afternoon. Afterward, experts put total damages at $500 million, with insured damages hitting $260 million.
For Affordable Homes of South Texas Inc. (AHSTI), a nonprofit developer, home builder, and mortgage company, the end of the storm was the beginning of a new problem. “What we found was that as a result of the damages that were left behind, a lot of our insurance premiums were either doubling or tripling or just not being renewed at all,” says Robert Calvillo, AHSTI’s executive director. “Carriers were leaving the area. Our existing [mortgage] customers . . . started having payment problems, delinquencies rising.”
Calvillo, who came to the affordable housing world after working in banking, suspected there might be creative ways to restrain AHSTI’s skyrocketing insurance costs. Calvillo’s first move was to try to sign up with an existing insurance company as a captive insurance agency, an arrangement similar to a franchise, in which an insurance agency is wholly owned by the entities it insures. But to Calvillo’s surprise, AHSTI was rebuffed.
“They wouldn’t even pay attention to us,” Calvillo remembers. “When I told them the agency would be owned by a nonprofit, they just they couldn’t wrap their head around it.”
Calvillo returned to the conventional insurance market and poked around. With premiums rising, he expected to find a competitive market, but what he found was the opposite—a rigid system, rife with inefficiency. “What we found was that some of the agents in the area, particularly . . . those type of agents that that are tied to one carrier, were really kind of stuck,” he says. “They couldn’t shop around. They couldn’t look for a better price.”
Calvillo saw opportunity, and decided to start his own firm, which he named Hope Insurance Agency. Other independent agents thought he was wasting his time, and predicted Hope would fold in a year or two. “The difference is that we decide what carriers we want to represent,” says Calvillo. “So as an example, we have approximately 12 carriers that will cover a typical home that we build. So if this one doesn’t want to do it because they’ve had losses or they only want to cover homes that are brick and masonry versus hardboard or whatever their appetite is, we can shop around. And so what we found was immediately . . . premiums are going back to where they were prior to the hailstorm and even lower than that.”
Almost a decade later, Hope is thriving. It currently has over 1,200 policies in force; approximately 60 percent of them are homeowners policies, the vast majority of which cover low- to moderate-income homeowners. Aside from its ability to shop between carriers, Calvillo attributes Hope’s success to the fact that its five agents are salaried rather than commission-based, and to the extensive industry experience of Hope’s former CEO, Rosie Ovalle (over 40 years in the insurance business) and its present one, Laura Rangel (over 20 years of experience). The benefits of AHSTI’s independent agency have proven to be durable; Calvillo estimates they’ve seen only a 30 percent increase in property insurance premiums in each of the past two years, a time during which many affordable housing properties have seen much larger increases.
A 30 percent increase is still a significant burden for most community developers, however, and a reminder that, while AHSTI has found a way to exploit inefficiencies in the system, it’s still working from inside that system, which is deeply and perhaps fundamentally flawed. The past several years have been punishing for many property owners, especially providers of affordable housing, who are required by their investors and lenders to carry high levels of insurance. They can’t simply raise rents to offset rising costs; even if they’re not restrained by statute, it’s not compatible with their mission of providing affordable housing. With some developers facing one-year increases as large as 450 percent, there’s widespread interest—some might say desperation—for potential solutions. There are fixes in the works—but will they come soon enough?
REINSURANCE REFORM
Reinsurance is a huge factor in recent premium increases. Sometimes called an invisible trade, reinsurance is essentially insurance for insurers; just as property owners buy insurance to protect themselves from a fire or earthquake, insurers purchase reinsurance to protect themselves from a large-scale disaster that could lead to a catastrophic number of claims. When you pay your insurance premium, a substantial part of it is passed through to reinsurers.
In some states, a majority of consumer insurance premiums are due to reinsurance costs; Birny Birnbaum, director for the Texas-based Center for Economic Justice, notes that “in Florida, it’s not uncommon to see an insurance company give 75 percent of its premium away” to reinsurers. In California, where some developers have seen 450 percent year-over-year increases in their premiums, Birnbaum speculates that “out of that 450 percent, maybe 50 percent is due to . . . inflation, and 400 percent is due to the reinsurance.”
Reinsurers can be ruthless when it comes to raising their rates. Spikes in global reinsurance prices don’t even seem to be predictably tied to increases in exposure, says Birnbaum. He refers, for example, to a graph of reinsurance costs known as the Guy Carpenter ROL Index. This graph shows spikes in costs after years that features heavy losses, followed by steady declines. “The rates spike after major events even though the risk was present when the insurers and reinsurers wrote the business,” he wrote in an email. “Did risk increase 50 percent from 2020 to 2024? . . . Did risk decline by two-thirds from 1993 to 2000? This is a market that, instead of pricing for future risk, seeks to recoup losses from bad years and then forgets about risk when there aren’t major events for a few years.”
Readily available reinsurance has enabled undercapitalized insurance companies to enter markets like California and Florida and essentially gamble on making a quick buck. “If you’re giving away 90 percent of your premiums to the reinsurance company, you can think of it as leverage,” explains Birnbaum. “You’ve got insurance companies that come in, particularly in Florida and Louisiana, and they roll the dice. They say, ‘We’re just going to buy tremendous amounts of reinsurance. The state is going to allow us to charge whatever we want . . . And if a big, big event hits, we walk away.’”
In 2023, the amount of capital in the reinsurance market hit a record $729 billion, which is why Birnbaum says, “in terms of affordable housing, reinsurance [reform] really would be the most immediate way to provide relief.”
But that’s easier said than done. The industry-leading reinsurance firms are based in Germany and Switzerland. You could look at this arrangement as beneficial—U.S. insurers are essentially exporting their risk, and when there’s a large-scale disaster in the U.S., the massive injection of foreign capital from reinsurance is a vital economic lifeline. But it does have its downside. While insurers in the U.S. are subject to state regulators and insurance law, reinsurance firms overseas are not.
What can the U.S. do to curb reinsurance costs? While it can’t regulate the companies directly, the U.S. government has intervened before. After 9/11, reinsurers stopped covering terrorism, forcing domestic insurers to follow suit. This abrupt reversal had a chilling effect on many industries, such as real estate and transportation. At the time, President George W. Bush attributed a lot of the post-9/11 recession to the withdrawal of reinsurance. Congress soon passed the Terrorism Risk Insurance Act, which required insurers to write policies covering terrorism, and also pledged federal funds as an emergency backstop in the event of a large-scale disaster.
There’s currently a bill working its way through the Senate that takes a similar approach. Written by California Rep. Adam Schiff, the INSURE Act sets up a federal reinsurance program that would absorb the top layer of risk—so, for example, policies from high-risk state insurers of last resort won’t have to get expensive private reinsurance. Instead, the federal government will price that reinsurance at the expected cost of claims, plus administrative costs. This will also take a lot of pressure off the rest of the market by removing that highest stratum of risk from private insurers’ books, which should further reduce prices. The act also sets aside a huge amount of government money for loss prevention and mitigation to blunt the ongoing effects of climate change, and to create means-tested financial assistance for property owners who are having difficulty affording insurance. (That assistance could take the form of loss mitigation, a buyout and relocation, or a simple cash transfer.) Finally, the act would collect granular data about the consumer insurance market. (Insurance regulators have long refused to collect this data, and so have very little actionable information about what’s happening in their markets.)
“The INSURE Act is actually a pretty comprehensive approach to addressing the problems,” Birnbaum says, noting that he’s bullish on the bill’s prospects of making it into law since its market-based logic should appeal to both sides of the aisle. But he also notes that it’s not a cure-all. “Reinsurance is one big piece of it, but reinsurance alone can’t solve the problem.”
STATE FALLBACKS
In most states, there are technically solutions already in place to handle situations like today’s out-of-control insurance market. Hard-hit states like Florida, Texas, and California have residual insurance markets for consumers who can’t get conventional insurance. These residual markets, like the FAIR plan in California, or Citizens in Florida, are intended as a backstop to handle spillover from what’s essentially a market failure. The problem is that most of them don’t work. Take California’s FAIR plan, for instance. The FAIR Plan is run by insurers and offers bare-bones policies covering only a few types of damage. There are not, however, any effective price controls; FAIR policies cost more than twice as much as private insurance.
It’s absurd. It’s like you’re rewarding the private market for limiting coverage.
Birny Birnbaum, Center for Economic Justice
Many experts say this kind of dysfunction could only be by design. “That’s the bizarre thing,” says Birnbaum. “These residual markets, they’re set up to punish policyholders who can’t get insurance in the voluntary market. The concept is that, well, we don’t want these residual markets competing with the private markets. So, you know, we’ll make them punitive. It’s absurd. It’s like you’re rewarding the private market for limiting coverage. It feels like saying we’re going to make the Affordable Care Act coverage punitive to consumers because they can’t get [medical] coverage through the voluntary market. Nobody would suggest something idiotic like that. But that’s the narrative that the property casualty insurers have gotten [through and] their narrative is adopted by insurance regulators around the country.”
Florida’s residual market, Citizens Insurance, has the opposite problem. Insurance through Citizens is actually much cheaper than buying it through a private company—37.5 to 44 percent cheaper, according Citizens. That’s because the Florida legislature froze state rates in 2010, and later restricted annual increases to 10 percent and then 12 percent. It sells both residential and commercial policies, and with rates frozen, is outcompeting the private market. Here the problem seems to be that it’s working so well that private companies resent the competition and have complained. In response, in December 2022, Florida’s state government began actively purging tens of thousands of people from Citizens’ rolls, canceling renewals for anyone who can access comparable private insurance that isn’t more than 20 percent more expensive than Citizens. The government has seemingly even sought to undermine Citizens’ reputation. Gov. Ron DeSantis told reporters recently that Citizens was “insolvent,” an alarming accusation that prompted calls for congressional hearings and was soon proved false.
So why are state insurers of last resort like Citizens and FAIR run like this—as safety nets that don’t actually offer much safety? Birnbaum and others point out that the insurance industry maintains a powerful lobby. Also relevant is that states take in a lot of money from the tax on insurance premiums.
“Premium tax is something on the order of 1.8 to 2 percent of premium,” says Birnbaum. “So it’s a gigantic revenue source for states.”
Most problems with the insurance system are quite complex, but here the remedy is fairly simple. Insurance is regulated on the state level, so state legislatures could pass legislative fixes, as they did to tamp down rates in Florida. (They would then have to hold more firm against industry complaints than Florida did.) In some areas, they already have. In Texas the state legislature has made it “much less punitive” for consumers who get insurance coverage for wind damage through the state, notes Birnbaum. “It’s simply up to the legislature. But the insurance industry fights it because they don’t want meaningful competition.”
There are relevant examples from the past, too. When Birnbaum was in a regulator in Texas in the early 1990s, he recalls, “there was a worker’s comp crisis. Companies were leaving the market. So the state created a public workers comp insurer, and that public worker’s comp insurer grew to something like 65 to 75 percent of the market. Well, no one complained because it was helping businesses. And eventually the private market came back. But, you know, it wasn’t a punitive approach. . . they offered a competitive product.”
Political pressure on regulators has to mount to a point that it outweighs industry influence.
The key factor here is that political pressure on regulators has to mount to a point that it outweighs industry influence. And with premiums skyrocketing around the country, it seems only a matter of time before many states reach that tipping point. In the meantime, many are looking at smaller-scale options.
Exempting nonprofits from sales tax on insurance would be a quick way to take some of the pressure off, says Daniel Elkin of cdcb, a Texas nonprofit developer. He says sales tax on insurance can run as high as $50,000 per building. “That just happens to be a weird part of the tax code that says, yes, you’re exempt from sales tax on physical materials, but services? No,” says Elkin. They are working with some state legislators to change that. “If it’s $50,000 a complex, it doesn’t solve the problem,” he says, “but it’s a lot of relief. And it seems like a pretty simple fix that nobody really loses on. I mean, I understand it’s less tax revenue. There’s repercussions for that. But at least for us, we get to keep affordable units in the market. And it’s not like the insurance companies are taking a hit.”
Risk Retention Groups
Self-insurance is a popular topic of conversation among many developers, but it comes with significant obstacles—the largest of which is the amount of capital you have to put down upfront. Many experts suggest self-insured entities set aside 200 percent of an insured property’s value upfront. Most developers of affordable housing don’t have twice the value of their buildings lying around; if they did, their insurance premiums wouldn’t be a problem.
Risk retention groups (RRGs) represent a sort of middle ground between self-insurance and getting a policy from a big corporation. RRGs were created by the Liability Risk Retention Act (LRRA) in 1986 as a response to the liability crisis of the 1980s, when spikes in medical and professional malpractice led insurance companies to drop many businesses. Those businesses, many of whom were national associations of doctors, lawyers, and dentists, complained that they could no longer get liability coverage, and asked Congress to do something. Congress proposed a hybrid structure, called a risk retention group, which allowed association groups to establish a type of captive insurance company—wholly owned by the clients they serve—that was licensed and regulated by one state but authorized to issue policies nationally.
This RRG structure had a number of advantages. It allowed participants to spread their risk across the country, which can bring costs down by diversifying the risk. And since the RRG serves a specialized pool of clients, it’s able to assess risks with far more precision. This is an especially important point, as nonprofits often complain that insurance companies don’t understand what they do, so they can’t write effective policies.
“I’ve been doing this for 35 years, insuring nonprofits, and I hear that still every day,” says Pamela Ellen Davis, founder, president and CEO of Nonprofits Insurance Alliance, a group of nonprofit insurance cooperatives that provide liability insurance to more than 25,000 nonprofit organizations in the U.S. “[They say], ‘Oh, my God, I can’t believe it has taken me so long to find you. No other insurance company understands what we are trying to do in the community,’” says Davis. “It’s like [insurance companies say] ‘you’re not a gas station, you don’t have four pumps, I don’t know what to do with you.’”
The catch here is that, at present, RRGs are only allowed to issue liability insurance. This is partly because they were spawned by a liability crisis, and partly a matter of industry preference.
“As I understand it,” says Davis, “the commercial insurance industry was making money on property and they were losing money on liability back in the mid-1980s. They reasoned that they weren’t going to be able to stop the LRRA from passing, so the compromise from the commercial carriers was, OK, let them do the stuff we can’t make money on anyway, but don’t let them do the stuff that’s profitable. No other good reason is evident from the historical record.”
But as with reinsurance, there’s a possible legislative fix in the works. The Nonprofit Property Protection Act is a discussion draft, circulated by Ohio Sen. Sherrod Brown, that would allow nonprofits to obtain property insurance through their RRGs as well. If the act becomes law, it would allow nonprofits an unprecedented degree of control over their property insurance. There’s also the possibility of savings, since the profit motive has been removed—though Davis stresses this shouldn’t be the main motivation behind forming an RRG.
“It’s more about access and control,” says Davis. “I never encourage anybody to start a risk retention group because they think they’re going to save a bunch of money. The claims are what the claims are, but you have control over that as a risk retention group to some extent. I mean, you have access to all your claims information, right? You know whether the members are paying too much or not. So it’s all about stability and getting the coverages that you need and deciding which risks you’re going to take. There’s no motivation to price gouge. The risk retention group that I lead is a 501(c)(3) nonprofit. I don’t have access to any of that money for my own personal gain. It’s all about figuring out what the right price is for the risk and charging that so that you can cover the claims and be financially solvent.”
And while RRGs have to buy reinsurance, they might pay less for it over time because of their specialization, according to Davis. “With reinsurers, it’s all about whether they trust the people that are doing the underwriting,” she says. “We have maintained really good reinsurance because we’re very transparent. . . . Risk retention groups are very focused on how they underwrite and understand the risks. . . . If they maintain the proper focus and discipline, they will be able to be more precise than a big commercial insurer that’s just kind of scattershot.”
To start an RRG, you need a business plan that’s approved by the state you’re domiciled in, plus a significant amount of data on the claims experience of your group members. Then you must produce an actuarial report conducted by an actuary approved by your state regulator. You’ll need to purchase reinsurance, and reinsurers need to have confidence that you have accurate data and have properly evaluated the risk. Then you’ll need a significant amount of capital; how much, exactly, depends on your risks and the regulatory demands as determined by regulatory risk-based capital standards. (Davis adds that affordable housing nonprofits could seek out capital from foundations.) The process of setting up an RRG typically takes at least six months—but once it’s up and running, participating nonprofits are free from conventional insurers.
But for property to be included in a RRG, the Nonprofit Property Protection Act has to pass, and for that to happen, Davis stresses, interested parties must unite and act now.
“We need the housing organizations to get behind the Nonprofit Property Protection Act (NPPA) and work with us,” she says. “We have organizations that are of all political stripes now experiencing this problem. We have to get people engaged and say, ‘This is what we need, and we’re willing to fight for it.’ I think we have more traction this year than we’ve had any year in the decade I’ve been working on this. . . . But it won’t happen unless everybody pulls together. We have a strategy that we are working on and we invite others to reach out to us . . . This has got to get done this year.”
The Reality of Rising Risk
For all the addressable factors driving up insurance costs, from reinsurance greed to regulatory malpractice to discrimination to simple inflation, there is, at base, the irreducible reality that in many areas of the country, risk is increasing. Until we face the consequences of a changing climate, fixes for insurance costs will be partial and temporary.
Some high-risk areas will likely become entirely uninsurable. (The government buyout and relocation section of the proposed INSURE Act is a tacit acknowledgment of this.) One insurance expert Shelterforce spoke with dryly noted that, from an actuarial standpoint, most of Florida is probably already uninsurable. The pendulum is swinging from a society in which most people can cheaply offload their worst risks to one in which risk mitigation is ever more a luxury good.
How bad today’s insurance crisis will get for affordable housing developers is largely going to be determined by how fast the system can accommodate this new reality: how fast government picks up the slack where private industry retreats, whether mortgage lenders and affordable housing investors will ease insurance requirements or let borrowers drown, and, of course, how soon we take steps to both slow climate change and reckon with those effects that are already inevitable.
Comments